Do people understand monetary policy?
“Improving the public's understanding of the central bank's policy strategy reduces economic and financial uncertainty and helps households and firms make more-informed decisions. Moreover, clarity about goals and strategies can help anchor the public's longer-term inflation expectations more firmly and thereby bolsters the central bank's ability to respond forcefully to adverse shocks.” (Bernanke, 2010).
Central bankers often emphasize the need to communicate with the public to improve their understanding of monetary policy. As the argument goes, this should allow households and firms to make betterinformed price- and wage-setting decisions, and improve policy effectiveness. More generally, agents' understanding of how policies that affect their decisions are conducted is perceived to be a key ingredient in the policy transmission mechanism. This perception is guided by economic theories in which thebehavior of the economy depends on the interaction between the actual conduct of policy and agents' understanding of it.
In a recent paper [1] we take a step back from the literature on central bank communication, expectations formation, and monetary policy effectiveness, and try to answer the more basic question of whether economic agents, U.S. households in particular, understand how the Fed conducts monetary policy.
We address the question of interest by combining households’ answers to survey questions about the direction of changes of future inflation, unemployment, and interest rates from the Survey of Consumers (“Michigan Survey”). To that end, we adopt an empirical approach that relies on simple regression anlisys.
To fix ideas, suppose that the Fed's target for the federal funds rate depends positively on contemporaneous inflation and negatively on contemporaneous unemployment, and changes only with these two variables. These are principles consistent with the so-called Taylor (1993) rule. Then, to be consistent with these relationships, survey answers that indicate that unemployment will go down and inflation will go up in one year would necessarily have to be accompanied by an answer that the Fed will tighten monetary policy over the same period.
We compare our findings with results obtained using actual interest-rate, inflation, and unemployment data. To that end, we use monthly data on the 3-month Treasury bill rate, 12-month CPI inflation, and the unemployment rate to build categorical variables indicating whether each of them moved up, down, or remained constant over each 12-month period.
The sample period for our analysis starts in August 1987 and ends in December 2007. The starting point coincides with the beginning of Alan Greenspan's tenure as chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, during which the Taylor rule came to be seen as a good description of U.S. monetary policy. The sample ends in December 2007 because the questions from the Michigan Survey pertain to 12-month forecasts, and at the end of 2008 short-term interest rates in the U.S. had essentially hit the zero lower bound.
Table 1 shows our first set of results. It presents the OLS-estimated coefficients for the categorized realized data and for the Michigan Survey. The Michigan Survey data are split between households at the lowest and highest income quartiles (results by education levels yield analogous patterns, with lower education households resembling those at the lowest income quartile and higher education households resembling higher income ones).
Focusing first on the realized data, the first column shows that the expected pattern is verified; changes in interest rates correlate positively with inflation and negatively with unemployment. The Michigan Survey data show a strong positive relationship between inflation and interest rates for both income groups. The unemployment coefficient, however, is only negative for higher income households.
These findings suggest that higher income households seem to perceive the patterns found in the data, and show that while the relationship between interest rates and inflation in the Michigan Survey answers is positive, irrespective of the demographics, the negative relationship between interest rates and unemployment is weaker.
One may ask if our regression results uncover the Fisher equation – a positive relationship between nominal interest rates and expected inflation – instead of a monetary policy rule. To investigate this possibility, we focus on higher income households, and estimate our regression pooling households by the year of interview. In particular, we are interested in exploiting the mid-2000s, during which Fed policy arguably deviated from a Taylor rule, keeping interest rates low and communicating that they would be in place for a “considerable period.”[2] If what households have in mind when answering the Michigan Survey is the Fisher equation, then the pattern of their answers should not change during such a period. Instead, if household answers reflect their perceptions on monetary policy, one should expect to see changes in households’ responses.
The top panel of Figure 1 reports the estimated coefficients for inflation, along with their 95% confidence bands, and the realized inflation rate (dashed, right axis). The bottom panel of Figure 1 reports the estimated coefficients of unemployment, 95% confidence bands and realized unemployment gap (dashed, right axis).
Consistent with the idea that these households’ responses reflect their perceptions of monetary policy, the inflation coefficients estimated year by year show that the strong positive relation holds for most of the sample, except during the mid-2000s, when it falls substantially and becomes statistically insignificant.
The estimated unemployment coefficients also yield an interesting pattern, showing that answers vary systematically over the business cycle. The negative relationship between interest rates and unemployment is much stronger and statistically significant during periods of labor market weakness.
Do these results mean that households understand the basic features of U.S. monetary policy? How to make sense of the statistical significance in our results, the degree of business cycle variation in the unemployment coefficient, and the change in the inflation coefficient during the mid-2000s?
Maybe households are “empiricists” and simply repeat patterns they observe in their own experiences. In that case they might end up responding as if they understand monetary policy. The other possibility is that at least some groups of households do understand monetary policy, but may be inattentive and only think about monetary policy at times when doing so may be worth its while, or at times when monetary policy is relatively more salient. These might be times in which the labor market is weak, and unemployment makes the headlines.
Irrespective of the drivers of the business cycle variation in the pattern of responses, we can conclude that households' beliefs about the evolution of inflation, unemployment, and interest rates – as elicited by the Michigan Survey – are related as if they had some understanding of U.S. monetary policy, particularly for the higher income (and more educated) households.
The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Federal Reserve System. E-mails: cvianac@econ.puc-rio.br, fernanda.nechio@sf.frb.org.
1. Carvalho, C. and F. Nechio (2014), “Do People Understand Monetary Policy?,” forthcoming at the Journal of Monetary Economics (working paper version: FRBSF Working Paper #2012-01 http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/files/wp12-01bk.pdf )
2. The Fed kept a constant target of 1% for the federal funds rate (between August 2003 and May 2004), and resorted to forward guidance to communicate that the target rate was expected to be maintained at this level for a “considerable period.” In addition, Taylor (2007) argues forcefully that, starting in early 2002, the Fed kept interest rates too low, and only reverted back to the level of interest rates that a Taylor-type rule would have implied by mid-2006.
References:
Bernanke, B. (2010), "Monetary Policy Objectives and Tools in a Low-Inflation Environment," Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (Revisiting Monetary Policy in a Low-Inflation Environment Conference).
Carvalho, C. and F. Nechio (2014), “Do People Understand Monetary Policy?,” forthcoming at the Journal of Monetary Economics (working paper version: FRBSF Working Paper #2012-01 http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/files/wp12-01bk.pdf )
Taylor, J. (1993), "Discretion versus policy rules in practice," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39: 195-214.
Taylor, J. (2007), "Housing and Monetary Policy," NBER Working Paper 13682.
