LAC’s Growth Prospects: Made in China?
The last ten years or so have been very good for many countries in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). They have witnessed the consolidation of a stable and resilient macro-financial framework, relatively high growth rates, and steps forward in the equity agenda. This new face of LAC was perhaps most clearly portrayed by a rather robust performance of the region, especially of South American countries, in the context of the recent global crisis. In effect, compared to the middle-income country average, the region’s recession in 2009 was relatively shorter lived and, with the notable exception of Mexico, remarkably mild and its recovery in 2010-2011 stronger.
Hence, a perfectly known and key question is whether LAC countries, that have so far experienced strong growth during the 2000s, can avoid a self-inflicted boom-bust pattern and rather turn what has been so far a vigorous cyclical recovery into a higher rate of trend growth. The very fact that these countries have been confronted at this stage with inflationary pressures arising from capacity constraints is a clear reminder of a rather sad reality—that the region tends to bump against “structural speed limits” at comparatively low growth rates. While the high-performing economies of emerging Asia can sustain annual growth rates in the 6-9 percent range without inflationary consequences, in most of LAC the non-inflationary growth rates that can be sustained over long periods tend to hover around 5 percent or lower.
In a just released report, “LAC’s Long-Term Growth: Made in China?”, we discuss whether LAC’s connection to China—dependent as it is on LAC’s natural resource abundance—can be capitalized so as to help the region enter into a steady process of economic convergence towards the standards of living of the advanced economies—a process that has systematically eluded LAC for more than a century. The robust growth observed in the region over the past decade is in fact an important reflection of this connection. Both directly (via trade and increasingly also FDI channels) and indirectly (mostly via China’s impact on the international commodity prices), China’s role in LAC is far from trivial. Coincidentally or not, productivity growth in the region has surged just as these links have deepened.
Hence, can LAC leverage on the China connection to escape the middle income trap? The short answer is so far, not really, but perhaps in the future, yes.
The intensification of trade and other economic links to China matter for sustainable growth only to the extent that they translate into factor accumulation and productivity increases, especially those associated with positive learning spillovers. LAC’s connection to China in the 2000s is reminiscent of that observed between the East Asian economies and Japan from the 1970s to the 1990. Contrasting these two situations can thus shed light on some of the potential spillover effects. Japan was a fast-growing neighbor with impressive technological progress in the postwar era that acted as a major growth pole, fostering growth in these countries for a long period of time.
Unlike the Japan-Tigers connection, we find thus far little evidence that China is fostering productivity growth in the LAC region in a similar fashion in which Japan did for the East Asian economies in the past. Let’s start with the trade connection. There is no meaningful intra-industry trade (a proxy for the extent of such spillovers effects) between LAC and China (Figure 1). A closer look at the composition of exports and imports between LAC and China show another hint of how this connection differs in nature from that of the Tigers and Japan. China, such as Brazil, Chile, and Peru, countries with more intensive trade, typically export primary products or natural resource-intensive goods and import large quantities of unskilled labor-intensive goods from China (Figures 2 and 3). Although China's technological sophistication is growing, the low intensity of advanced technologies in the imports from China suggests limited potential for technological spillovers. In sharp contrast, the majority of East Asian economies back in 1990 not only imported from Japan large amounts of technology-, capital-, and skill-intensive goods, but also exported them.
The China-LAC and Japan-Tigers connections appear to differs with respect to FDI growth spillovers, with the former rather limited and concentrated on the acquisition of large firms in natural resource-based industries, In contrast, the golden years of East Asian Tigers were characterized by large flows of intra-industry trade and FDI flows, which led to the development of network-type connections with Japan and among themselves, and significant diffusion of technology and knowledge.
In spite of the disheartening aggregate depiction of LAC's current connections with China, there are some clear bright spots. There is growing case-study evidence of significant technological modernization, clustering effects, and linkages to other sectors in the production of agricultural commodities in the region—in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Uruguay, for example. And there is hard evidence of significant movement up the value chain in the production of mineral commodities—with LAC’s share in the global exports of higher value added (“worked”) metals increased eightfold over the past 30 years or so.
Developing clustering and production chains bring not only direct benefits, such as employment generation and direct local value added, but also important indirect ones. They can act as catalysts for not only technology and knowledge enhancement but also capacity-building and economic development more widely, thus leading to virtuous cycles. While LAC seems to be on the right track, these achievements are still small in comparison to the connectivity developed by the Tigers. Since their early stages of development in the mid-1980s, East Asian countries were highly active in creating linkages and upgrading their production and have been at the center of global value chains in industries such as electronics and semiconductors.
In sum, while China may be fostering growth in the region by simply absorbing our commodity exports, sustaining their prices, and driving the expansion of LAC’s commodity-based exporting industries, it has played a much more limited role in the diffusion of technology and knowledge spillovers. A central point for policymakers is that trade connections alone—i.e., connections that are not accompanied by, and lead to, human capital formation, investments in innovation, technological adoption and adaptation, and cumulative learning—are unlikely to spur productivity growth. And even more so when export revenue expansion relies solely on buoyant prices of high-rent commodities.
Learning (to produce more and better of the same, and to produce new things) in a globalized economy can come from any place, and not just the export destination country, if the right institutional and policy environment is in place. The absence of the latter may explain why LAC has already missed an opportunity when it could not capitalize on the tight connection it has maintained with the U.S.—a rich and innovative economy operating at the technological frontier—for much of the post-World War II era. Are there deeper institutional and structural reasons that make LAC economies less able to learn and absorb technology? Much of the Region’s handicap is related to lags behind in human capital, skills, infrastructure, and innovation capacity. The new connection to China will then by itself not change these deficiencies. That is the job of a well-designed and implemented growth-oriented policy agenda, an agenda that is by and large still missing.
Moving forward, even in a context of trade based on comparative advantage forces with China, LAC countries have the potential to leverage their connection to China and make the connection a blessing, though LAC faces a tall order in this regard. The overriding challenge in the growth front for LAC’s policymakers is thus to harness the opportunities afforded by deeper and broader links to the global economy in general, and to China in particular. In the shorter run, how LAC manages the mature phase of the recovery cycle will be crucial in this respect, as it would set the stage for the implementation of a more robust long-run growth agenda. Beyond the short run, the premium on productivity enhancing policies will need to be raised. Some of the key external conditions for LAC to raise its growth rate sustainably above the world’s average may be in place (large and growing countries with strong demand for LAC exports; high commodity prices; and low world interest rates). Seizing the opportunity on this favorable external environment will require well-designed, but not necessarily numerous or unduly complex, policies to ignite growth that are adequately tailored to the circumstances of each individual country. The productivity-oriented policy effort however needs to be particularly large to compensate for structural impediments to a competitive exchange rate, namely low domestic savings and high financial integration. The effort needs to be much larger in fact than that of the Tigers, which followed a different model: high domestic savings and limited integration into non-FDI international markets.
Figure 1. The Degree of Intra-Industry Trade with Growth Poles
Figure 2. Composition of Imports from Growth Poles
Disclaimer: Any opinion and conclusion expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Board of Directors or the countries they represent.
Reference:
De la Torre, A., T. Didier, C. Calderon, S. Pienknagura, T. Cordella, C. Aedo, and I. Walker, 2011. “LAC’s Long-Term Growth: Made in China?” Biannual Report of the Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America of the World Bank.
